Stamp duty was one of the triggers for the American Revolution. Somehow, 250 years later, we still have it. That makes no sense – it raises no money, is pointlessly complex, and creates cost and uncertainty for business. The Government should abolish it.
250 years ago, stamp duty made perfect sense. The State had limited power and resources, and collecting tax from people was hard. So some unknown genius had a brilliant idea. Impose a special duty on documents. No need to have an army of tax inspectors. But if you wanted the document to be used for any kind of official purpose, you’d have to pay to get it stamped. No official would accept an unstamped document, for fear of being thrown into jail. Beautiful simplicity – a tax that doesn’t need an enforcement agency.
Stamp duty once applied to basically everything. Even tea1Technically this was the Townshend Act not the Stamp Act, but facts shouldn’t get in the way of a good engraving – which helped spark the American Revolution. Over time, it’s shrunk and shrunk, and today it’s basically irrelevant. But still there, and still costing business millions in legal fees.
At this point I should clarify that I’m talking about old-style stamp duty, the one that actually involves things being stamped2Post-pandemic, it’s an electronic stamping rather than physical stamping – HMRC retired their beautiful old stamping machines.. I’m not talking about the two modern taxes that emerged from stamp duty, but work in a sensible modern way:3By which I mean that, whilst not great taxes from a policy standpoint, they technically/practically work just fine. They were created because stamp duty just became too old, creaking, and easily avoided. They are “normal” taxes in that if you don’t pay them, you go to jail (maybe). stamp duty reserve tax (SDRT – which applies to shares), and stamp duty land tax (SDLT). Both are often referred to as “stamp duty”, but they are separate taxes.
What does old-style stamp duty actually cover?
Given SDRT applies to securities, and SDLT applies to land, what does stamp duty do?
Answering that question is surprisingly hard, and requires a level of nerdy detail not really suitable for a blog post or twitter thread. But it demonstrates the insanity of the tax, so I’ll do it anyway:
- The principal charging clause is paragraph 1 of Schedule 13 to Finance Act 19994This was created as part of a rather half-hearted and very incomplete consolidation of legislation in 1999. Believe it or not, things used to be worse. This says that stamp duty is chargeable on a transfer on sale, and paragraph 7 extends that to some agreements for sale. So at this point we think: OMG stamp duty applies to everything.
- But then section 125 Finance Act 2003 says that actually stamp duty is abolished on everything except instruments relating to “stock and marketable securities”. Whew – it only applies to some stuff.
- But what kind of stuff? The definition of “stock and marketable securities” is in section 122 of the Stamp Act 1891, which reads pretty much like you’d expect from 150-year-old legislation:
The expression “stock” includes any share in any stocks or funds transferable by the Registrar of Government Stock, any strip (within the meaning of section 47 of the Finance Act 1942) of any such stocks or funds, and any share in the stocks or funds of any foreign or colonial state or government, or in the capital stock or funded debt of any county council, corporation, company, or society in the United Kingdom, or of any foreign or colonial corporation, company, or society.
The expression “marketable security” means a security of such a description as to be capable of being sold in any stock market in the United Kingdom
- If you stop and squint at this long enough, you’ll probably conclude it means that stamp duty applies to shares and bonds.5But only “probably” – there’s a reason why I’ve have seen twenty-page opinions on at least four different words in the definition of “stock”
- But don’t stop there, because section 125 is partially undone by paragraph 31 of Schedule 15 to Finance Act 2003 which says that certain partnership transactions are also subject to stamp duty, if the partnership holds stock or marketable securities.
- And we’re still not done, because the George Wimpey & Co case says that options can sometimes be subject to stamp duty, for reasons which don’t make a huge amount of sense, but there we go.6What exactly does Wimpey do following the partial abolition of stamp duty by s125 FA 2003? Good luck.
- And where’s the rule actually saying you have to pay stamp duty? There isn’t one. Stamp duty’s “teeth” are found in section 14(4) Stamp Act 1891, which says that a document executed in the UK, or which relates to the UK, can’t be used for any purpose in the UK unless it is stamped. So, for example, a share registrar won’t recognise a transfer of shares unless you get the transfer stamped. And a court won’t accept a document as evidence if it is stampable, but hasn’t been stamped. In principle your multibillion £ deal could be unenforceable if stamp duty isn’t paid, which would be awkward.7This has never, to my knowledge, happened to a large transaction, but it has created injustice on a small scale – see for example the recent Highscore case – thanks to
Nicholas Ostrowski for alerting me of this in the comments below.
I should emphasise – this unholy mess just tells us what the tax applies to. How it’s calculated, how the timing works, the scope of the exemptions – they make the above look simple and rational, but are a subject for another day.
So what does this mean in practice?
There are two ways in which stamp duty is actually relevant.
First, whenever shares in an unlisted UK company are bought/sold. People actually pay this, and get their documents stamped – because if they don’t, the transfer couldn’t be registered. But if stamp duty was abolished tomorrow, SDRT would apply instead. So in this scenario, stamp duty is payable but pointless.8The interaction between stamp duty and SDRT is another deeply fascinating area.
Second, there’s a whole universe of cases where stamp duty might apply if you were really unlucky, but in practice never does. Some examples:
- Transactions in foreign securities. The UK has no business taxing these transactions, and SDRT (stamp duty’s sensible sister) certainly doesn’t. Stamp duty in theory does tax transactions in Upper Volta, if the transactions have a UK party or are signed in the UK (or otherwise “relate” to the UK, whatever that means). But people normally don’t care – the fact you can’t enforce such a transaction in a UK court doesn’t much matter if the securities are foreign (i.e. because you’d enforce in the relevant foreign court).
- A document might be thought to contain an “option”, and so be technically stampable, even though it’s not realistically an option at all.
- Sales of loans, for example where a bank is selling part of its business to someone else. In practice the loans will almost always be exempt, but establishing this to a level of legal certainty means reviewing each loan. If the purpose of a tax system is to ensure revenue for tax lawyers, then job done.
I have never once seen stamp duty actually paid on any of this second class of transactions. But I’ve seen huge amount of time/money spent analysing the issues. Why? Because if a document is stampable but the duty isn’t paid, then it’s unenforceable. On a large commercial transaction that’s an unacceptable risk.
So there we have it. Stamp duty applies to some transactions pointlessly, and applies to other transactions not at all.
But all this complexity is an expensive business. During my 25 year career as a tax lawyer, I’m pretty confident I charged at least £2m in fees for stamp duty advice9I am thinking something like – an average of at least £100k/year x 25 years. Obviously, it’s not money I personally received.. I will modestly say it was excellent advice, and my clients were very happy with it – but multiply this across all the tax lawyers in the UK, and that’s a lot of wasted fees on a pointless tax.
Full credit to The Office of Tax Simplification, who made this kind of argument five years ago (and were ignored).
So what should the Government do?
Abolish stamp duty. It’s an easy win: a tax-simplifying, pro-investment, pro-growth policy that costs nothing and has no downside.
It’s not even technically difficult. Expand the SDRT payment/collection rules so SDRT more easily applies to paper transactions in unlisted UK shares. Tidy up the SDRT rules that rely upon stamp duty.10There are quite a few – SDRT doesn’t have many exemptions, so “hooks in” to stamp duty exemptions – these would have to be preserved. Job done.
Is this really the stupidest tax?
No, I lied. It’s the second stupidest.
The very stupidest is bearer instrument duty – a kind of a miniature clone of stamp duty for bearer instruments. In a world where SDRT exists, bearer instrument duty is completely irrelevant and I have never seen any actually paid. For added relevance, real bearer instruments basically don’t exist anymore. The tax is in Schedule 15 Finance Act 1999 and I have not the slightest clue why it still exists.
Why haven’t both these taxes been abolished?
Hard to say. Most bad tax rules exist because someone benefits from them – perhaps HMRC, perhaps a few deserving and/or loud taxpayers. But in this case there is literally no point to stamp duty. I can only assume the calculation for HMRC is: no downside for us in keeping it in place11Because whether someone stamps a document or decided by the taxpayer – HMRC has zero compliance cost; work for us in repealing it.
If so, that’s the wrong calculation. Stamp duty should join the old stamping machines in graceful retirement.
Engraving of the Boston Tea Party by E. Newbury, 1789, photo by Cornischong
-
1Technically this was the Townshend Act not the Stamp Act, but facts shouldn’t get in the way of a good engraving
-
2Post-pandemic, it’s an electronic stamping rather than physical stamping – HMRC retired their beautiful old stamping machines.
- 3
-
4This was created as part of a rather half-hearted and very incomplete consolidation of legislation in 1999. Believe it or not, things used to be worse
-
5But only “probably” – there’s a reason why I’ve have seen twenty-page opinions on at least four different words in the definition of “stock”
-
6What exactly does Wimpey do following the partial abolition of stamp duty by s125 FA 2003? Good luck.
-
7This has never, to my knowledge, happened to a large transaction, but it has created injustice on a small scale – see for example the recent Highscore case – thanks to
Nicholas Ostrowski for alerting me of this in the comments below. -
8The interaction between stamp duty and SDRT is another deeply fascinating area
-
9I am thinking something like – an average of at least £100k/year x 25 years. Obviously, it’s not money I personally received.
-
10There are quite a few – SDRT doesn’t have many exemptions, so “hooks in” to stamp duty exemptions – these would have to be preserved
-
11Because whether someone stamps a document or decided by the taxpayer – HMRC has zero compliance cost
Comment policy
This website has benefited from some amazingly insightful comments, some of which have materially advanced our work. Comments are open, but we are really looking for comments which advance the debate – e.g. by specific criticisms, additions, or comments on the article (particularly technical tax comments, or comments from people with practical experience in the area).
9 responses to “The stupidest tax: complicated, costs businesses £m, and raises zero money. Let’s abolish stamp duty.”
Great article, this is fascinating.
One question – do you have any idea what the savings might be if old ‘stamp duty’ was abolished and simply replaced with SDRT (with the exemptions etc rolled into it)? As in rather than the at least £2 million you think you may have charged for legal advice on old ‘stamp duty’, how much might you have charged if SDRT was in place instead?
I assume there might still be some uncertainty in the system, especially in some niche marginal cases but on the whole a lot of legal advice that is currently needed for old ‘stamp duty’ would no longer be required?
It would be good to try and work out some (admittedly very rough!) figures for what the aggregate saving might be.
My £2m figure is for stamp duty advice specifically – I also advised on SDRT but that is normally simpler. So the “Dan saving” for abolishing stamp duty would certainly be at least £2m over 25 years. I wondered if there was a way to estimate a whole-economy saving, but there would be so many assumptions it would end up as pure guesswork. I’m guessing in the region £10-50m/year? But I would feel like a fraud publishing any number like that…
Brilliant stuff Dan, I love a good bit of history. But history should be exactly that, history, not an active policy that still affects case law today! Tis’ hilarious that it’s still in effect right now and could potentially mess up massive transactions.
Great article and I agree. For a recent example of the carnage this can cause businesses see the June 2022 decision of Leech J in Mannering v Highscore [2022] EWHC 2257 where the lack of stamping of a share transfer form *in 2007* was said to make the document inadmissible as evidence before the court (full disclosure, I was counsel to the successful Respondent).
Re: your footnote 7, I think you’re wrong – unstamped documents have been held to be inadmissible in Semple v Semple [2006] CSOH 180 and McGuane v Welch [2008] EWCA Civ 785 albeit in quite unusual circumstances.
Crikey, I was completely unaware of the Highscore case. Clearly dropped the ball post-retirement!
But I should have remembered Semele. I’ll update!
Hi Nicholas – interesting case, new to me too. I see your client won the appeal, notwithstanding the stamp duty point being raised. I’m surprised that a stock transfer form from 2007 was still available, and I’d have said the written-up share register was the best evidence of share ownership, not possession of an old share certificate. But could any stamping foot-fault have be corrected by simply paying any applicable stamp duty now? I’d need to check where the law stood then, but if it was a gift for nil consideration, the duty might be just £5 or nil anyway. There might also be a penalty to pay – perhaps £300. Rather cheap in the context, I suspect.
On whether the UK should charge stamp duty or not, there is some HMRC administrative cost, in reviewing the forms and payments that sent to the Stamp Office (electronically nowadays), but it is pretty efficient for HMRC to collect. People literally send money to HMRC. Many jurisdictions impose some sort of transfer tax or registration fee on share transfers, so why not.
But that is no reason to stick with antiquated legislation. It is slightly amusing that the Stamp Act 1891 remains important, but so does the Partnership Act 1890 and the Offences Against the Person Act 1861. Stamp taxes missed the kind attention of the Tax Law Rewrite Project. The time for a proper consolidation and rationalisation is long past.
Just to put some numbers on it, in 2021/22, SDLT raised about £14 billion, SDRT was about £3 billion, and stamp duty was about £1.5 billion. Most private share sales are low value, but some can be large – £100 million or more – so the amounts can be pretty chunky. It is small beer in the grand scheme of things (beer excise duty raised about £3.7 billion – but stamp duty on its own was more than the bank levy, or air passenger duty, or landfill tax, or the digital services tax, or aggregates levy, or the soft drink levy, or diverted profits tax – and more than several of the smaller ones combined. More indeed than we might raise by taxing carried interest as income.)
SDRT applies to almost all UK share transfers, but the charge on non-listed share transfers is usually “franked” by payment of stamp duty on a written stock transfer form. Is Dan suggesting that people transferring UK shares should engage with paying SDRT by the “accountable date” under the SDRT Regulations instead? Would that be better from a taxpayer perspective? It wouldn’t be collected automatically like it is on listed shares – so someone would have to do a tax return.
If we did abolish stamp duty, there would be some peculiarities in SDRT to iron out – for example, there is no SDRT equivalent of s.42 stamp duty group relief (which necessitates the rather arcane workaround that is the “letter of direction”).
Yes, I’d scrap stamp duty, roll exemptions into SDRT, and create sensible payment regulations/procedures for unlisted shares (eg online submission system).
Perhaps one of the fundamental reasons UK taxes are high and the level of services so low is chronically bad leadership. The idea that civil servants are employed in an “office of tax simplification” to review the way things are done and make recommendations for process improvement sounds so impressive. If the work is done and the recommendations ignored it is a scandalous waste. The Minister in charge should be fired.
The problem is widespread. I complained about the absurd process to pay additional voluntary contributions for my pension and after months of pressure was told
“I have explored all of the options available to me but have been unable to ascertain the reason for the CF83 form not being available for online completion. It is only available in its current PDF format via the gov.uk website which I know you are already aware of. We do appreciate your feedback and it will be kept on file should the NI38/CF83 be reviewed in the future. I am sorry that I have been unable to explain the reason why the CF83 is not available online and I do understand your frustration that it lengthens the process for applying to pay voluntary contributions. ” (this was in 2021)
Reeks of lack of accountability, irresponsibility, and tolerance of shoddy standards.
I also keep running into “this particular scenario requires you to file on paper”. It’s infuriating!