The UK taxes high-earning lawyers less than bankers. That’s irrational – and illustrates a wider problem with the tax system. It’s hard to change, but we’d all benefit if we taxed all income in the same way.
Here’s the problem:
- A City law firm has £100m of profits to share between 100 partners.1Some people unfamiliar with City law firms may be shocked at how large these figures are; some people who work in City law firms may regard this as a poor level of profitability, and possibly a failing firm. The tax consequence: each partner has gross income of £1m on which they pay £435k income tax2i.e. tending towards the 45% top marginal rate, plus £35k national insurance3Tending towards the 2% marginal rate. So the lucky partners take home £530k4It will usually be less than this, because law firms – like most businesses – have non-deductible expenditure… in practice that will raise the effective tax rate by a couple of %, and lucky HMRC collects £47m.
- A bank has £100 million of profits to share between 100 traders. The tax consequence: the bank pays employer’s 13.8%5There’s a good argument I should add the 0.5% apprenticeship levy, because it does behave just like another 0.5% employer’s NI. But, given it’s semi-hypothecated, I decided to leave it out. If you disagree with me on this, then that means my bigger argument has 0.5% more force. national insurance, leaving £87.9m for the bankers.6I made a bad mistake here, and added the 13.8% employer’s NI to the £100m. That makes no sense, because the bonus pool was stated to be £100m – the bank is going to have to use that to pay the bonuses and the employer’s NI. Now corrected! So each banker has a gross income of £879k, on which they pay £380 income tax and £21k national insurance. So the poor bankers take home £477k, and even more lucky HMRC collects £52.3m.
The lawyers have an overall effective tax rate of 47%; the bankers’ rate is 52.3%. That is an odd and irrational result.
Why does it happen? The simple reason is that partners in a law firm are not employees, and so there’s no 13.8% employer’s national insurance.7Some people will complain at this point that the bankers aren’t paying employer’s national insurance – so why include that in their effective tax rate? The answer is that the economic evidence suggests that, in the long run, the economic incidence of employer’s national insurance largely falls on wages. In my example it’s particularly clear – the bank has a bonus pool, and the employers are going to get what’s left after employer’s national insurance is paid – so it is directly reducing their income. This isn’t tax avoidance, or even tax planning8Except when it is – see the smart comment from ‘Tigs’ below regarding salaried “partners” – it’s an inevitable consequence of the fact that our tax system puts so much weight on whether a person is an employee.
The question is whether we should change the law and tax partners in law firms and other large professional firms the same way as employees.
How much tax could we raise?
The Lawyer has crunched the numbers on large law firms, and reckon that the top 50 UK law firms and top 50 US law firms have a combined UK profit of £6.3bn, implying that if they were subject to employer’s national insurance, that would yield an additional £870m of tax.
The top 75 UK accounting firms have a profit of around £3bn, implying an extension of employer’s national insurance would yield an additional £400m of tax.
Add in management consultants, investment managers, and other large professional partnerships (whether in partnership or corporate form) and it’s realistic to think we’d be looking at between £1.5bn and £2bn of revenue.9There would certainly be difficult edge cases; this post is about the principle rather than the practicality. Similarly, lots of points to think about re. non-deductible expenditure, which for some large partnerships already takes the effective rate over 50%.
Should we do it?
Given the economic mess we currently find ourselves in, it’s hard to defend £1m lawyers paying less tax than other comparable professionals.
As Catrin Griffiths, editor of The Lawyer, says:
All the data points to the fact that commercial law is a highly successful UK sector that relies on an infrastructure of education, training and technology. In a climate of rising taxes for all, law firms will be increasingly challenged to consider their own financial contribution to the public finances.
Politicians may find the prospect of an easy £2bn of additional revenue tempting.
And yet I pause at the idea of creating a headline tax rate of over 50%. On the one hand, that’s already what happens – the bankers in my example above have an effective rate of 53.5%. But – and this is important – they probably don’t feel like they do.
Wider implications – and solutions
It’s not just lawyers. The same distortions and difficulties arise throughout the economy.
We tax employment income much more than other types of income, and that creates distortion, uncertainty, and tax avoidance. I’ve no doubt that employer’s national insurance is a Bad Tax and we should end it.
But if we immediately abolished national insurance, and rolled it into income tax, then I fear many people would be aghast at how much tax they were paying (even if employers passed-on the benefit of the employer national insurance cut, which is distinctly optimistic). Tax psychology is a thing, and (on the basis of no evidence) I worry about the overall economic and fiscal effects of people feeling like they’re paying more in tax than they take home. That’s not a reason not to act, but it’s a reason to be very cautious.
This is a hard problem.
There are two things that might make it easier:
- First, make the change mostly revenue-neutral. We’d be greatly expanding the base of people paying the 13.8% tax. So we don’t need the rate to be as high as 13.8% to collect the same amount. My feeling (and tax policy needs more than a feeling) is that nobody should be paying a marginal rate of over 50%.
- Second, mandate that employers pass on the savings. This would be a highly unusual thing to do, but in this circumstance, it might be realistically achievable10The usual problem is this: when the 5% “tampon tax” was abolished, we couldn’t legally require that prices were cut by 5%, because retail prices move all the time, and it’s not possible to disentangle the tax cut from other price changes. Wages are different. It might (and this would need a lot of thought) be possible to require employers pass on an employer’s national insurance cut. That wouldn’t be a perfect solution, because an employer could pass on the cut, but at the same time scrap a wage rise that otherwise would have been paid. But it could (particularly in a time of low inflation) ensure that most of the benefit went to employees in the short term, and there’s good reason to believe that it will go to employees in the long term regardless of what we do.
This would have two effects. People who aren’t employees would see a tax rise, but it would be less than the full 13.8%. Employees would see an actual tax cut. It’s just about possible this could make the whole proposal politically feasible. Maybe.
All we need is a suitably courageous politician.
Image by DALL-E: “a statue of lady justice, with a stack of dollar bills in her hand, digital art”
-
1Some people unfamiliar with City law firms may be shocked at how large these figures are; some people who work in City law firms may regard this as a poor level of profitability, and possibly a failing firm.
-
2i.e. tending towards the 45% top marginal rate
-
3Tending towards the 2% marginal rate
-
4It will usually be less than this, because law firms – like most businesses – have non-deductible expenditure… in practice that will raise the effective tax rate by a couple of %
-
5There’s a good argument I should add the 0.5% apprenticeship levy, because it does behave just like another 0.5% employer’s NI. But, given it’s semi-hypothecated, I decided to leave it out. If you disagree with me on this, then that means my bigger argument has 0.5% more force.
-
6I made a bad mistake here, and added the 13.8% employer’s NI to the £100m. That makes no sense, because the bonus pool was stated to be £100m – the bank is going to have to use that to pay the bonuses and the employer’s NI. Now corrected!
-
7Some people will complain at this point that the bankers aren’t paying employer’s national insurance – so why include that in their effective tax rate? The answer is that the economic evidence suggests that, in the long run, the economic incidence of employer’s national insurance largely falls on wages. In my example it’s particularly clear – the bank has a bonus pool, and the employers are going to get what’s left after employer’s national insurance is paid – so it is directly reducing their income.
-
8Except when it is – see the smart comment from ‘Tigs’ below regarding salaried “partners”
-
9There would certainly be difficult edge cases; this post is about the principle rather than the practicality. Similarly, lots of points to think about re. non-deductible expenditure, which for some large partnerships already takes the effective rate over 50%.
-
10The usual problem is this: when the 5% “tampon tax” was abolished, we couldn’t legally require that prices were cut by 5%, because retail prices move all the time, and it’s not possible to disentangle the tax cut from other price changes. Wages are different. It might (and this would need a lot of thought) be possible to require employers pass on an employer’s national insurance cut. That wouldn’t be a perfect solution, because an employer could pass on the cut, but at the same time scrap a wage rise that otherwise would have been paid. But it could (particularly in a time of low inflation) ensure that most of the benefit went to employees in the short term, and there’s good reason to believe that it will go to employees in the long term regardless of what we do.
11 responses to “The first thing we do, let’s tax all the lawyers.”
I note your concern about creating a headline tax rate of over 50% but this is already the case for some employees when student loan is also factored in: something which was covered by general taxation for the generation of senior partners in professional service firms. So the answer might be to rename it? Young well paid graduates may have a marginal tax rate of 40% tax, NIC of 2% and student loan of 9%.
Of course – as I am sure you appreciate – it is really a lot more complicated than this. Not least because partners not only work for the firm, but they are the firm’s proprietors too. So, your analogy with bankers ought to have treated part of the income of partners as earnings, and part as a distribution of profits (dividend) – and the dividend element would not attract NICs on any basis. There is also the fact that for partners, their share of profits does not equate to cash drawings. Cash-flow is retained within the firm for working capital – and in a corporate analogy would be taxed at CT rates (and not subject to NICs).
Of course, you are right that in an ideal world, the choice of entity through which to conduct business should be tax neutral – the taxation suffered by stakeholders in a business should not depend on the legal form through which the business is undertaken. But the reality is that this ideal is unlikely ever to be achieved because businesses are messy, and different legal forms create different kinds of relationships.
Maybe we should wind the clock back to 1856 and limit the number of partners in a firm to 20 – or treat firms with more than 20 partners as if they were companies for direct tax purposes? You would still need to consider how much of the firm’s profits were to be treated as partners’ earnings, and how much as dividend.
I think Tigs makes some very sensible points but isn’t quite right at 1. Whilst lots of UK partners will get US profits (with no Class IV NICs as from a wholly overseas partnership – not what you’d have had at CC, Dan), lots of US partners will get UK profits and not pay NICs (for obvious reasons). The logical fix on this (NICs on profits regardless of source) just adds to the bounty of these proposals.
You might be right. But in the US law firms I’ve seen the US firm’s UK LLP will typically make very small profits. A UK partner who works in the UK LLP might received US$4.95m from the US part of the firm and U$0.05m from the UK part of the firm. Ratios of profits that I’ve seen are in the 99%:1%, 95%:5% range.
As for the profits of the US firm received by UK partners not being subject to class 4 (and also only being taxed on a remittance basis for non-doms) that’s just silly. And from what I’ve seen, unlikely to withstand proper scrutiny. For example, if the US employees and partners come to the UK for depositions, meeting clients, having board meetings, etc and the UK partners (who are partners in the US firm too) supervise US staff then how can the US firm’s trade be said to be carried on “wholly” outside the UK?
Completely take the point about whether the “wholly overseas” partnership stands up to scrutiny (there’s a decent argument it does) – I think based on current practice it is accepted that (rightly or wrongly) it does and Class IV isn’t being paid on those profits when it might be more equitable that it is paid, perhaps as Dan says with some form of employers NI on top also.
Of course, the other oft-cited issue is that the over-65s don’t pay NIC. So by shifting the burden to income tax you push those people into paying more tax than they otherwise would. Obviously a policy choice – but as was seen this lunchtime with the preservation of the Triple Lock, a highly unlikely one from a Conservative government relying on that demographic’s vote!
Thanks Dan, some random thoughts:
1. The profits from the “top 50 US firms” is likely to significantly understate the profits that the UK partners receive as a signficant proportion of those profits (e.g. 95%) come from the US partnership rather than the UK partnership.
2. An employer would pay 0.5% apprenticeship levy too.
3. You say “The simple reason is that partners in a law firm are not employees, and so there’s no 13.8% employer’s national insurance. This isn’t tax avoidance, or even tax planning”. I disagree with this. A large proportion of partners in law firms (especially the more junior ones) rely on failing Condition C of the salaried member rules to prevent PAYE/employer’s NIC due. The capital they contribute (funded by loans from a bank that has an arrangement to do this) is carefully designed and managed to ensure that it is sufficient to fail Conditon C. If that is not tax planning then nothing is.
4. Edge cases are always interesting but I’d want to make sure that people could not get around the rules by changing the form of their firm (e.g. a UK LLP becomes a US LLP).
5. Why not add PAYE to cash distributions too? That would accelerate the money that the goverment gets in too.
6. If you don’t like the employer’s NIC concept on partners, why not increase the 2% marginal class 4 NIC rate by 8% or 9% (equivalent to an extra 13.8% less tax relief)?
thanks! Interesting points. You have me bang to rights on point 3 – I was taking my experience at CC (where there are no UK salaried partners) and forgetting it’s far from universal. I’ll add a footnote.
Hypocritical that you say this five minutes after leaving a law firm.
Kinda, yes – although law firm partners are paid in arrears, so I’m still receiving partnership income, and this change (were it to happen) would affect me (until next May) .
So how exactly would poor Dan have been expected to publish such an article whilst still in the partnership at CC?